What liberal economists get wrong about Brexit
Sorry, Paul Krugman: This really is a morality play
Britain will vote on June 23 on whether to leave the European Union. One of the major reasons is that EU policymaking has been an absolute catastrophe for the last seven years, particularly with respect to the eurozone countries of southern Europe.
Since the eurozone crisis began in 2009, liberal economists like Paul Krugman have repeatedly wrung their hands over the moralizing of northern European creditor nations. Elites from Germany and France explained the crisis with an argument that southern European nations like Greece and Italy behaved irresponsibly, and the brutal austerity imposed on them by eurozone elites was merely just deserts for their wrong behavior.
Counter-posed to this moral narrative, Krugman and company put forward a technocratic explanation. By their reading, the problem with the eurozone is simply poor mechanical design. Moral narratives must not be allowed to intrude on value-neutral analysis: "Economics is not a morality play," to quote one of Krugman's signature phrases.
Subscribe to The Week
Escape your echo chamber. Get the facts behind the news, plus analysis from multiple perspectives.
Sign up for The Week's Free Newsletters
From our morning news briefing to a weekly Good News Newsletter, get the best of The Week delivered directly to your inbox.
From our morning news briefing to a weekly Good News Newsletter, get the best of The Week delivered directly to your inbox.
Their technical analysis of the faults with the eurozone is very convincing. But this explicit disavowal of morality is ethical nonsense and politically blinkered. One cannot possibly understand why the eurozone has failed, much less counter the rise of revanchist nationalism, without promulgating a morally grounded alternative.
Take the conservative argument against foreclosure relief, which says that people who borrow are morally obligated to repay the money. Liberal economists respond with a slew of often-confusing arguments that such a position doesn't make technical sense. They say debt writedowns can increase overall output and employment under certain conditions, a debt overhang can leave lasting economic damage, economy-wide debt reduction will be systemically challenging during recession conditions, and so on.
All these arguments are correct. But they are also non-responsive to the basic impulse animating the conservative position — that some people are getting a bailout they don't deserve. It's not too hard to construct a simple moral argument that supports the technocratic arguments. Steve Randy Waldman has one: Creditors are just as responsible as borrowers for bad loans. This replaces a false morality play with a better one, placing blame where it is due and laying the foundation for a more just policy.
That brings me back to the eurozone. It is true, of course, that the euro was not designed according to the dictates of optimum currency area theory, and that recent eurozone policy has been stunningly inept from a technocratic perspective. Practically everything done to Greece by eurozone elites has been a failure according to their own definition of success.
But the euro crisis has also featured an endless parade of gross moral atrocities, especially on the part of the eurozone leadership. It was odious to put the entire blame for a Europe-wide crisis at the foot of southern European countries who had only a partial share of the blame (particularly when eurozone elites knew all about the shadiness of the Greek government when it was admitted). It was odious to force brutal austerity on countries when it was perfectly obvious it would only make their debt problem worse. It was odious to breathe life into dying ethnonationalist stereotypes to distract from the great sins of French and German banks. It was odious to overthrow the government of Italy. It was odious to deliberately cause a bank run in Greece to coerce the Syriza government into ignoring the results of a popular referendum. (As T.S. Eliot once wrote, "It is impossible to design a system so perfect that no one needs to be good.")
Most of that goes unnoticed by Krugman in a recent column arguing against Brexit; instead he laments the German "morality play" once more.
Economics — like any first-rank policy question — is unquestionably a morality play. The only question is what kind. Arguments about whether or not Britain should remain in the EU should of course take technical questions — like what might happen to trade — into account. But human beings are moral animals. Portraying one's own position as uninterested in moral questions — or worse, actively immoral — is to set oneself up for defeat.
Sign up for Today's Best Articles in your inbox
A free daily email with the biggest news stories of the day – and the best features from TheWeek.com
Ryan Cooper is a national correspondent at TheWeek.com. His work has appeared in the Washington Monthly, The New Republic, and the Washington Post.
-
Joe Biden's legacy: economically strong, politically disastrous
In Depth The President boosted industry and employment, but 'Bidenomics' proved ineffective to winning the elections
By The Week UK Published
-
Crossword: November 17, 2024
The Week's daily crossword
By The Week Staff Published
-
Sudoku hard: November 17, 2024
The Week's daily hard sudoku puzzle
By The Week Staff Published