How the failed Halliburton-Baker Hughes deal reveals the problem with mergers

In capitalism, sometimes mergers are just cheats

Mergers are not always successful.
(Image credit: Fanatic Studio / Alamy Stock Photo)

A $28 billion mega-merger between oil field services giants Baker Hughes and Halliburton went down in flames this weekend. How it happened raises some big questions not just about the two companies but about the very wisdom of mergers themselves.

Halliburton and Baker Hughes are the second and third-biggest companies in the world when it comes to supplying technology and assistance to oil drilling projects. But the field's leader is Schlumberger, and one key goal of the combination was to better rival that company's market share.

This is where the problems begin to come in. Baker Hughes in particular had bits of technology Halliburton hadn't been able to equal in its fight against Schlumberger. Combining was one obvious way to solve the problem. But that also meant there would be fewer companies in the field attempting to provide those technologies to customers. And U.S. government regulators pointed to between 23 and 30 lines of products and services where the number of competitors would drop from three to two, quite possibly leading to less choice and higher prices.

Subscribe to The Week

Escape your echo chamber. Get the facts behind the news, plus analysis from multiple perspectives.

SUBSCRIBE & SAVE
https://cdn.mos.cms.futurecdn.net/flexiimages/jacafc5zvs1692883516.jpg

Sign up for The Week's Free Newsletters

From our morning news briefing to a weekly Good News Newsletter, get the best of The Week delivered directly to your inbox.

From our morning news briefing to a weekly Good News Newsletter, get the best of The Week delivered directly to your inbox.

Sign up

They brought the hammer down in early April, when the Justice Department filed an antitrust suit to block the merger. "I have seen a lot of problematic mergers in my time. But I have never seen one that poses so many antitrust problems in so many markets," Bill Baer, the head of the Justice Department's Antitrust Division, said in a conference call at the time.

Halliburton and Baker Hughes both being international heavyweights, authorities in Brazil and Australia voiced issues with the proposed deal as well. The European Union even opened an official antitrust investigation into the merger back in January.

The companies tried to deal with regulators' objections by selling off various business lines to other players. But the recent collapse in oil prices meant everyone was hunkering down, so Halliburton and Baker Hughes couldn't find enough willing buyers. Under all that combined pressure, they called off the deal on Sunday.

Here's what's curious about this tale. Ostensibly, the ultimate point of free market competition is to benefit everyone. Capitalism is not supposed to be a pleasant experience for the companies operating in it. Under constant pressure to maintain market share, keep customers, and turn a profit, they must ceaselessly innovate new technologies and business models, which then percolate through all of society and make us all better off. Profits are just the second-order effect of all this: They're the result of a company doing better by society as a whole, and thus the incentive that drives companies to keep improving things for everyone.

That's the theory anyway.

But Halliburton and Baker Hughes' deal is an example of how this theory can fall apart in practice. The other guy builds a better mousetrap, but instead of reacting to that development by attempting to build an even better mousetrap, you just buy out the other guy. It works great for your bottom line. But in terms of how capitalism is supposed to operate, it's kind of a cheat — a way to get around the hard work of actually competing.

So while profits are supposed to be the crucial link between the capitalist's self-interest and the common good, they're not always so beneficent. Left to its own devices, that link can break down, and capitalists can make a profit while hurting the common good.

In the instance of mergers and mega-deals, there are few ways this can happen.

One obvious example in which fewer and bigger companies can profit even while making everyone else worse off is natural monopolies: a market where, for whatever reason, it's just intrinsically difficult for competitors to enter. So whoever's already there can charge customers an arm and a leg without adding any value. Another example is when regulatory barriers keep competition out of a market — so established players aren't leveraging new innovations to their advantage when they raise prices, they're just leveraging new government rules.

A third example, less talked about, is when the economy is just in a chronic slump of weak aggregate demand. Lots of people are perpetually out of work, so employees have no bargaining power to demand raises or better compensation. There's always somebody more desperate ready to take whatever deal they won't take. On top of that, the weak economy offers fewer real opportunities for profitable investment. Put it all together, and companies have both fewer labor costs and fewer investment costs, so they just spit out all the excess revenue to shareholders.

There are lots of random events that drive waves of mergers — sudden new technologies or upheavals in industry, or super-low interest rates that make it cheaper to do the borrowing necessary for corporate buyouts.

But I think the evidence that a chronic lack of demand is responsible for our latest wave of mergers and acquisitions is pretty overwhelming. Think of it this way: High demand in the economy drives competition, because opportunities to provide for customers' needs proliferate so fast companies can't keep up if they don't innovate and pay their workers better to retain them. But when demand is low, companies can extract more in profits by combining forces.

One justification you often here for mergers is to cut down on operating costs. Which is of course true. One company is, by definition, less bureaucracy than two companies. But that's also just another way of the companies saying: We don't feel any demand from the economy right now to bother building our own better mousetrap, so we might as well combine offices and give the shareholders the savings.

None of which is to say a merger or acquisition is never a good idea. Just that, when the people who stand to profit say "both companies expected the proposed merger to result in compelling benefits to shareholders, customers, and other stakeholders," as Halliburton Chairman and CEO Dave Lesar said, there's reason to be skeptical.

And reason to be glad that the U.S. government, which has long demurred from vigorously enforcing antitrust law, might finally be getting its mojo back.

To continue reading this article...
Continue reading this article and get limited website access each month.
Get unlimited website access, exclusive newsletters plus much more.
Cancel or pause at any time.
Already a subscriber to The Week?
Not sure which email you used for your subscription? Contact us
Jeff Spross

Jeff Spross was the economics and business correspondent at TheWeek.com. He was previously a reporter at ThinkProgress.